In economics, the Cobb–Douglas functional form of production functions is widely used to represent the relationship of an output to inputs. Similar functions were originally used by Knut Wicksell (1851–1926), while the Cobb-Douglas form was developed and tested against statistical evidence by Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas during 1900–1947.
Contents |
In its most standard form for production of a single good with two factors, the function is
where:
Output elasticity measures the responsiveness of output to a change in levels of either labor or capital used in production, ceteris paribus. For example if α = 0.15, a 1% increase in labor would lead to approximately a 0.15% increase in output.
Further, if:
the production function has constant returns to scale: Doubling capital K and labour L will also double output Y. If
returns to scale are decreasing, and if
returns to scale are increasing. Assuming perfect competition and α + β = 1, α and β can be shown to be labor and capital's share of output.
Cobb and Douglas were influenced by statistical evidence that appeared to show that labor and capital shares of total output were constant over time in developed countries; they explained this by statistical fitting least-squares regression of their production function. There is now doubt over whether constancy over time exists.
Paul Douglas explains that his first formulation of the Cobb–Douglas production function was developed in 1927, when seeking a functional form to relate estimates he had calculated for workers and capital, he spoke with mathematician and colleague Charles Cobb who suggested a function of the form previously used by Knut Wicksell . Estimating this using least squares, he obtained a result for the marginal productivity of labour (k) to 0.75$ --- which was subsequently confirmed by the National Bureau of Economic Research to be %74.1. Later work in the 1940s prompted them to allow for the exponents on C and L vary, resulting in estimates that subsequently proved to be very close to improved measure of productivity developed at that time.[1]
A major criticism at the time was that estimates of the production function, although seemingly accurate, were based on such sparse data that it was hard to give them much credibility. Douglas' remarked "I must admit I was discouraged by this criticism and thought of giving up the effort, but there was something which told me I should hold on."[1] The breakthrough came in using US census data, which was cross sectional and provided a large number of observations. Douglas presented the results of these findings, along with those for other countries, at his 1947 address as president of the American Economic Association. Shortly afterwards, Douglas went into politics and was stricken by ill health --- resulting in little further development on his side. However, two decades later, his production function was widely used, being adopted by economists such as Paul Samuelson and Solow.[1] The Cobb–Douglas production function is especially notable for being the first time an aggregate or economy-wide production function had been developed, estimated, and the presented to the profession for analysis; it marked a landmark change in how economists approached macroeconomics.[2]
The Cobb–Douglas model is criticized by some Austrian economists such as William Barnett II on the basis of dimensional analysis. They argue it does not having meaningful or economically reasonable units of measurement unless .[3] However, other economists in reply to Barnett have argued that the units used are not fundamentally more unnatural than other units commonly used in physics such a log temperature or distance squared.[4]
The Cobb–Douglas production function was not developed on the basis of any knowledge of engineering, technology, or management of the production process. It was instead developed because it had attractive mathematical characteristics, such as diminishing marginal returns to either factor of production and the property that expenditure on any given input is a constant fraction of total cost. Crucially, there are no microfoundations for it. In the modern era, economists try to build models up from individual agents acting, rather than imposing a functional form on an entire economy. However, many modern authors have developed models which give Cobb–Douglas production function from the micro level; many New Keynesian models, for example.[5] It is nevertheless a mathematical mistake to assume that just because the Cobb–Douglas function applies at the micro-level, it also always applies at the macro-level. Similarly, it is not necessarily the case that a macro Cobb–Douglas applies at the disaggregated level. An early microfoundation of the aggregate Cobb–Douglas technology based on linear activities is derived in Houthakker (1955).[6]
Nonetheless, the Cobb–Douglas function has been applied to many other contexts besides production. It can be applied to utility[7] as follows: U(x1,x2)=x1αx2β; where x1 and x2 are the quantities consumed of good #1 and good #2.
In its generalized form, where x1, x2, ... ,xL are the quantities consumed of good #1, good #2, ..., good #L, a utility function representing the Cobb–Douglas preferences may be written as:
with x = (x1, x2, ... ,xL). Setting and because the function is strictly monotone for x > 0, it follows that represents the same preferences. Setting it can be shown that The utility may be maximized by looking at the logarithm of the utility which makes the consumer's optimization problem:
This has the solution that:
which has the interpretation that the per-unit fraction of the consumers incomes used in purchasing good j is exactly the marginal term
The Cobb–Douglas function form can be estimated as a linear relationship using the following expression:
Where:
The model can also be written as
As noted, the common Cobb–Douglas function used in macroeconomic modeling is
where K is capital and L is labor. When the model coefficients sum to one, as in this example, the production function is first-order homogeneous, which implies constant returns to scale, that is, if all inputs are scaled by a common factor greater than zero, output will be scaled by the same factor.
The translog production function is a generalization of the Cobb–Douglas production function. The name translog stands for 'transcendental logarithmic'.
The three factor translog production function is:
where L = labor, K = capital, M = materials and supplies, and q = product.
Constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function:
corresponds to a Cobb–Douglas function,
Proof:
Apply l'Hôpital's rule:
Therefore,